Prepare the following article for translation in the tutorials
The next capitalist revolution
CAPITALISM HAS suffered a series of mighty blows to its reputation over the past
decade. The sense of a system rigged to benefit the owners of capital at the
expense of workers is profound. In 2016 a survey found that more than half of
young Americans no longer support capitalism. This loss of faith is dangerous,
but is also warranted. Today’s capitalism does have a real problem, just not the
one that protectionists and populists like to talk about. Life has become far
too comfortable for some firms in the old economy, while, in the new economy,
tech firms have rapidly built market power. A revolution is indeed needed—one
that unleashes competition, forcing down abnormally high profits today and
ensuring that innovation can thrive tomorrow.
Countries have acted to fuel competition before. At the start of the 20th
century America broke up monopolies in railways and energy. After the second
world war West Germany put the creation of competitive markets at the centre of
its nation-building project. The establishment of the European single market, a
project championed by Margaret Thatcher, prised open stale domestic markets to
dynamic foreign firms. Ronald Reagan fostered competition across much of the
American economy.
A similar transformation is needed today. Since 1997 market concentration has
risen in two-thirds of American industries. A tenth of the economy is made up of
industries in which four firms control more than two-thirds of the market. In a
healthy economy you would expect profits to be competed down, but the free
cashflow of companies is 76% above its 50-year average, relative to GDP. In
Europe the trend is similar, if less extreme. The average market share of the
biggest four firms in each industry has risen by three percentage points since
2000. On both continents, dominant firms have become harder to dislodge.
Incumbents scoff at the idea that they have it easy. However consolidated
markets become domestically, they argue, globalisation keeps heating the furnace
of competition. But in industries that are less exposed to trade, firms are
making huge returns. We calculate the global pool of abnormal profits to be
$660bn, more than two-thirds of which is made in America, one-third of that in
technology firms (see Special report).
Not all these rents are obvious. Google and Facebook provide popular services at
no cost to consumers. But through their grip on advertising, they subtly push up
the costs of other firms. Several old-economy industries with high prices and
fat profits lurk beneath the surface of commerce: credit cards, pharmaceutical
distribution and credit-checking. When the public deals with oligopolists more
directly, the problem is clearer. America’s sheltered airlines charge more than
European peers and deliver worse service. Cable-TV firms are notorious for high
prices: the average pay-TV customer in America is estimated to spend 44% more
today than in 2011. In some cases public ire opens the door to newcomers, such
as Netflix. Too often, however, it does not. Stockmarkets value even
consumer-friendly entrants such as Netflix and Amazon as if they too will become
monopolies.
Rising market power helps solve several economic puzzles. Despite low interest
rates, firms have reinvested a stingy share of their bumper profits. This could
be because barriers to competition keep out even well-funded newcomers. Next,
since the turn of the millennium, and particularly in America, labour’s share of
GDP has been falling. Monopolistic prices may have allowed powerful firms to eat
away at the purchasing power of wages. The labour share has fallen fastest in
industries with growing concentration. A third puzzle is that the number of new
entrants has been falling and productivity growth has been weak. This may also
be explained by a lack of competitive pressure to innovate.
Some argue that the solution to capital’s excesses is to beef up labour.
Elizabeth Warren, a possible American presidential candidate, wants to put more
workers on boards. Britain’s Labour Party promises compulsory employee
share-ownership. And almost everyone on the left wants to reinvigorate the
declining power of unions (see Briefing). There is a role for trade unions in a
modern economy. But a return to 1960s-style capitalism, in which bloated
oligopolies earn fat margins but dole cash out to workers under the threat of
strikes is something to be avoided. Tolerating abnormal profits so long as they
are distributed in a way that satisfies those with power is a recipe for
cronyism. Favoured insiders might do well—witness the gap between coddled
workers and neglected outsiders in Italy. But an economy composed of cosy
incumbents will eventually see a collapse in innovation and hence a stagnation
in living standards.
......
https://www.economist.com/leaders/2018/11/15/the-next-capitalist-revolution